Wednesday, May 29, 2013

Guided Entrepreneurship

  My year-long industrial leave from UC Berkeley to Teknekron in 1969-70, which I described last month, whetted my appetite for a continuous liaison with industry.  It was largely sated by my quarter-century relationship with that company. 

  Shortly after its founding and my involvement with its first project, Teknekron became a unique platform for entrepreneurship.  The concept, as envisioned by its CEO, was to find young would-be entrepreneurs who needed more than just capital, those who could also benefit from the entrepreneurial training the company had to offer and from its connections to the market and to research institutions.  The process, as it unfolded, became known as guided entrepreneurship.  That may seem like an oxymoron, since entrepreneurs are not thought to be easily guided.  Teknekron showed otherwise.  Although the company is now inactive (all of its principals retired in 1995), its methodology is still worth chronicling, for it increases the chance of entrepreneurial success.

  Guided entrepreneurship is very different from other start-up strategies.  Venture capital concentrates on discovering inventors who already have a product in mind and primarily need capital to develop it and bring it to market.  Corporate spin-outs attempt to enhance and market products invented within an existing company through a newly formed enterprise.  Incubators provide a bevy of facilities to entrepreneurs: space; infrastructure such as communication and computer equipment; legal, accounting and other support; and often a modicum of capital, business advice and market access. 

  Teknekron's methodology differed markedly by concentrating not on products but on entrepreneurial minds.  It sought smart young people who weren't bent on retreating to a back room to develop a product from an idea, or—if they were—could be persuaded to drop that focus.  Those it brought into the company after careful screening were go-getters who at the very outset would be willing, with the company's guidance, to address prospective clients in the marketplace—in our case, large corporations—to find needs that could be filled by the broad knowledge they had.

  The novelty in Teknekron's "market first" approach is encapsulated in the difference between the motifs "Sell, Design, Build" (SDB) and "Design, Build, Sell" (DBS).  All other start-up models take the DBS path—money and other resources are poured into turning an idea into a finished product and then trying to sell it into a preconceived market, which might not have been there after all.  Teknekron's SDB approach instead insisted that if an idea has enough worth, that worth could be established by finding a client which would be willing to fund its development for the client's business.  Its entrepreneurs weren't allowed to develop products in a vacuum, assuming that a market for them would somehow be forthcoming

  Teknekron's program hence trained entrepreneurs to go first to the market in search of problems that needed solving; sell a proposed solution to a problem thus discovered; develop that solution into client-specific hardware, software, and operational procedures; and only then consider generalizing the technology into a more broadly applicable product.  The company brought value to the process not only by providing financial,  marketing, infrastructure and professional support to the entrepreneurs, but most importantly by enforcing a market-oriented and profit discipline.. 

  Knowing the general area of expertise of new entrepreneurs, Teknekron would introduce them to prospective clients and teach them above all to listen for needs, not to advocate technologies.  They might play an opening gambit like "I have an idea for a better mousetrap," but if the response was, "I have no mice, but I do have foxes that are invading my henhouses," Teknekron's training would lead them to segue seamlessly into attacking the fox problem.  The immediate effort—with Teknekron's negotiating and legal help—would be to sell a contract for solving that problem (usually series of phases, starting with a feasibility study).  It was expected that, in solving the particular problem, a more-generic technology for solving other problems would emerge.  Teknekron always insisted that its contracts reserve to itself the rights for those other applications of the developed technology, giving the client royalties from other sales of the original application.

  The new entrepreneurs were initially employees of Teknekron.  Once they had built up sufficient revenues and profitability, they got their own corporation, which would be a subsidiary of Teknekron in which they and their colleagues owned shares.  After a subsequent stage of growth to another benchmark of revenues and profitability, the new corporation would be spun out by public or private sale, yielding the payout that both Teknekron and the entrepreneurs sought.  When successful, the time from a one- or two-person start-up to its public or private sale averaged about ten years.  Teknekron's profit discipline was strict: if a new venture did not reach the first benchmark of sales and profitability within a year or at most two, it was terminated; most reaching that benchmark subsequently achieved the second. 

  All of Teknekron's start-up companies addressed information-technology issues, in such varied industries as energy utilities, commercial and investment banking, transportation, communications and insurance.  It is hard to precisely assess the success rate the company had, since one tends to forget the businesses that were shut down early, but my educated guess is that some 35-40% of start-ups jumped both hurdles, reaching the sale stage.  The success rate was thus a significant multiple of that expected of venture capital, although the time to final payout was longer.  Teknekron considered itself more of a marathon runner than a sprinter.

  I was privileged to participate in many roles in the guided-entrepreneurship program for a quarter century, mostly while I was on the faculty at UC.  I brought a number of my academic colleagues into new ventures as technical advisors; I was able to bring some of the brightest students in my department into those ventures upon their graduation; I participated both in the work of technology development and in the process of guiding the entrepreneurs; and I continued consulting for companies that had spun out of Teknekron by public or private sale.  After I retired from the University, I spent the final seven years of my career full time at the company.

  As I said in describing that first year of industrial leave, the tripartite relationship I maintained with Teknekron and the university became indispensable to my professional career, for it enabled me to keep one foot in research and one in market applications.  I like to think that the interplay between those complementary roles brought value to the economy as a whole by helping the process of technology transfer from universities and other research institutions.  I believe that engaging in that interplay is a valuable model for engineering and science faculty members.